|
[1] Aguiar, M., & Hurst, E. (2007). Measuring Trends in Leisure: The Allocation of Time over Five Decades. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122(3), 969-1006. [2] Aguiar, M., Hurst, E., & Karabarbounis, L. (2013). Time use during the great recession. The American Economic Review, 103(5), 1664-1696. [3] Barsky, R., House, C. L., & Kimball, M. (2003). Do Flexible Durable Goods Prices Undermine Sticky Price Models? (No. w9832). National Bureau of Economic Research. [4] Barsky, R. B., House, C. L., & Kimball, M. S. (2007). Sticky-price models and durable goods. The American Economic Review, 97(3), 984-998. [5] Barsky, R. B., Boehm, C. E., House, C. L., & Kimball, M. S. (2015). Monetary Policy and Durable Goods. Working paper. [6] Benhabib, J., Rogerson, R., & Wright, R. (1991). Homework in Macroeconomics: Household Production and Aggregate Fluctuations. Journal of Political Economy, 99(6), 1166-1187. [7] Bils, M., & Klenow, P. (2004). Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Prices. Journal of Political Economy, 112(5), 947-985. [8] Bridgman, B. (2013). Home Productivity. Manuscript, Buerau of Economic Analysis. [9] Calvo, G. A. (1983). Staggered prices in a utility-maximizing framework. Journal of Monetary Economics, 12(3), 383-398. [10] Cantelmo, A., & Melina, G. (2015). Monetary Policy and the Relative Price of Durable Goods. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 5328. [11] Carlstrom, C. T., & Fuerst, T. S. (2010). Nominal rigidities, residential investment, and adjustment costs. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 14(01), 136-148. [12] Chang, Y. (2000). Comovement, excess volatility, and home production. Journal of Monetary Economics, 46(2), 385-396. [13] Chen, B. L., & Liao, S. Y. (2014). Capital, credit constraints and the comovement between consumer durables and nondurables. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 39, 127-139. [14] Clarida, R., Galí, J., & Gertler, M. (1999). The Science of Monetary Policy: A New Keynesian Perspective. Journal of Economic Literature, 37(4), 1661-1707. [15] Erceg, C., & Levin, A. (2006). Optimal monetary policy with durable consumption goods. Journal of Monetary Economics, 53(7), 1341-1359. [16] Fisher, J. D. (2007). Why does household investment lead business investment over the business cycle?. Journal of Political Economy, 115(1), 141-168. [17] Gaumont, D., Wright, R., & Zhu, Y. (2016). House Price Rigidity. Working paper. [18] Gomme, P., Kydland, F. E., & Rupert, P. (2001). Home production meets time to build. Journal of Political Economy, 109(5), 1115-1131. [19] Greenwood, J., & Hercowitz, Z. (1991). The Allocation of Capital and Time over the Business Cycle. Journal of Political Economy, 99(6), 1188-1214. [20] Gwin, C., & VanHoose, D. D. (2012). Durable goods and sticky prices: Industry-level evidence. Economics Letters, 116(3), 460-464. [21] Huffman, G. W., & Wynne, M. A. (1999). The role of intratemporal adjustment costs in a multisector economy. Journal of Monetary Economics, 43(2), 317-350. [22] Klenow, P. J., & Malin, B. A. (2010). Microeconomic evidence on price-setting. Handbook of Monetary Economics 3A, B. Friedman and M. Woodford ed.: Elsevier, 2011, 231-284. [23] Lester, R. (2014). Home production and sticky price models: Implications for monetary policy. Journal of Macroeconomics, 41, 107-121. [24] Monacelli, T. (2009). New Keynesian models, durable goods, and collateral constraints. Journal of Monetary Economics, 56(2), 242-254. [25] Nakamura, E., & Steinsson, J. (2008). Five Facts about Prices: A Reevaluation of Menu Cost Models. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(4), 1415-1464. [26] Taylor, J. B. (1993, December). Discretion versus policy rules in practice. In Carnegie-Rochester conference series on public policy (Vol. 39, pp. 195-214). North-Holland. [27] Tsai, Y. C. (2016). What Do Working Capital And Habit Tell Us About The Co-movement Problem?. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 20(1), 342-361.
|